Share

Trade: Beware mercantilist sentiments

One of the most profound (and often most difficult to teach) insights in economics is the idea that trade is not a zero-sum game.

Just as my salary allows me to purchase all the things I cannot (or don’t want to) produce on my own, so our exports (of the things we are good at) allow us to buy imports (of the things we are not good at). We do not work simply to accumulate a salary; we work because it allows us to buy nice things.

In other words, we are not mercantilists. A mercantilist hopes to export as much as possible and restrict imports. A large, positive trade balance, they believe, will “make a nation rich”.

Not so. Mercantilism is not why England experienced an Industrial Revolution, and it is not why Africa will grow rich. Having more exports than imports over the long run simply means that a country’s citizens are not reaping the fruits of their labour. To return to the earlier metaphor: it’s like earning a salary but not being allowed to purchase anything with it.

It’s easy to sell mercantilist ideas, though. Here is Alexander Wilmot in the Legislative Council of the Cape Colony in August 1891: “Let us be wise in time, and really patriotic, grow our food, encourage our own industries…” Or John Xavier Merriman, the last prime minister of the Cape Colony, in the same debate: “The best form of protection was for everybody to set to and buy as much as they could in the colony. (Hear, hear.)”  

You don’t need to go too far to find similar sentiments in contemporary debates. The clothing and textile industry recently held an Imbizo to discuss ways to grow the industry. Some of the comments on news websites reporting this story summarise the sentiment I often find in my classes too: “Chinese imports killed the textile industry in South Africa”, “You forget the greedy retailers preferring the cheapest suppliers”, “All we need is a 90% buy local campaign”, “With a bit of goodwill and assistance in the form of import restrictions we would all benefit. Jobs, better quality and some pride in the achievement would do all of us some good!”

Again, not true. 

Aside from the small detail that the industry has received support since the 1930s, long before China was a competitive force, we should rather export what we are good at, and import the cheap goods which we aren’t relatively good at. (Also, Chinese clothes are becoming increasingly expensive as Chinese wages increase. We are increasingly importing clothes from other parts of Asia and Africa.)

But how do we do this? Two recent UNU-Wider working papers by South Africa’s foremost trade economists help to answer exactly this question. 

The first, by a team of economists from North-West University and Stellenbosch University, use a new firm-level dataset of South African manufacturers to understand exporting firms better. 

They report five key findings:

1) Export participation is rare – only 19% of South African firms export.

2) Exporters are systematically different to non-exporting firms – they are larger, more labour productive, pay higher wages, and are more capital and intermediate-input intensive than non-exports. I will lump all these things together and just say they are “better”.

3) Firms that export to multiple destinations and across multiple product lines are “better” across all the dimensions listed above.

4) Exporters to countries outside Africa are “better” across the same dimensions than exporters to countries within Africa.

5) Firms that already export are most likely to grow the total value of exports than new entrants.

The second paper, by researchers at the University of Cape Town and the University of Bari in Italy, use similar data to show that the most productive South African firms are the ones that both import and export. Importing from advanced economies especially makes local firms more productive, and more likely to export at greater scale, scope and value. The authors argue that access for domestic firms to a variety of intermediate inputs from abroad can be crucial to raising local employment and gaining access to new technologies.

The take-away: South Africa’s exporters need imports to be competitive. We can only grow our local exporting firms by giving them access to the cheapest inputs and the best technologies, and these are often found outside SA. Much like our 19th-century ancestors, our zest to expand exports will only inflict harm if we adhere to the mercantilist sentiment by restricting imports.

Johan Fourie is associate professor in Economics at Stellenbosch University.

This article originally appeared in the 14 July edition of finweek. Buy and download the magazine here. 

We live in a world where facts and fiction get blurred
Who we choose to trust can have a profound impact on our lives. Join thousands of devoted South Africans who look to News24 to bring them news they can trust every day. As we celebrate 25 years, become a News24 subscriber as we strive to keep you informed, inspired and empowered.
Join News24 today
heading
description
username
Show Comments ()
Rand - Dollar
19.08
+0.4%
Rand - Pound
23.61
+0.9%
Rand - Euro
20.33
+0.3%
Rand - Aus dollar
12.25
+0.4%
Rand - Yen
0.12
+0.4%
Platinum
943.10
-0.8%
Palladium
1,030.50
+0.1%
Gold
2,388.47
+0.4%
Silver
28.68
+1.6%
Brent Crude
87.11
-0.2%
Top 40
67,314
+0.2%
All Share
73,364
+0.1%
Resource 10
63,285
-0.0%
Industrial 25
98,701
+0.3%
Financial 15
15,499
+0.1%
All JSE data delayed by at least 15 minutes Iress logo
Company Snapshot
Editorial feedback and complaints

Contact the public editor with feedback for our journalists, complaints, queries or suggestions about articles on News24.

LEARN MORE
Government tenders

Find public sector tender opportunities in South Africa here.

Government tenders
This portal provides access to information on all tenders made by all public sector organisations in all spheres of government.
Browse tenders